Theoretical Logic and Policy Practice of Digital Economy Driving the Improvement of Macroeconomic Governance System — An Analysis Based on Marx’s Theory of Social Reproduction

Authors

  • LIU Hang School of Economics and Finance, Xi’an Jiaotong University, Xi’an 710061, China
  • GAO Fei School of Accounting and Finance, The Open University of Shaanxi, Xi’an 710119, China
  • MA Pin School of Economics and Finance, Xi’an Jiaotong University, Xi’an 710061, China

DOI:

https://doi.org/10.20069/ff78px02

Keywords:

digital economy, macroeconomic governance, theory of social reproduction, capital accumulation, new quality productive forces

Abstract

The research question of how the digital economy can effectively promote changes in the organizational and institutional arrangements of social production and empower the modernization of governance systems and capabilities at all levels holds significant research value. Currently, there is little research on the digital economy’s role in driving macroeconomic governance changes. The digital sector and the physical sector are interconnected within the physical value chain and the innovation value chain, with unique exchange and competition relationships. In the macroeconomy, the digital sector is susceptible to output fluctuations during investment and financing exposure periods or industry cycle nodes, leading to broader economic fluctuations, which may render traditional macroeconomic control measures ineffective. The distinctive operational rules of the digital economy necessitate timely updates to macroeconomic governance and innovative implementation of macroeconomic policies in terms of ideas, methods, and means.

This article uses Marx’s theory of social reproduction as a foundation to construct a four-part reproduction model that includes digital production and its downstream sectors. It deduces the macroeconomic operation mode, policy tools, and governance system under the digital economy. The research findings include: 1) Increased capital accumulation in the digital factor production sector drives growth in other sectors and overall output. 2) Faster technological progress in the digital consumer goods production sector accelerates capital accumulation in the digital factor sector, promoting total output growth. 3) Capital accumulation in the digital factor sector has a ratchet effect on total output growth, indicating that even a one-time increase in capital accumulation can continue to provide a positive supply shock to the macroeconomy. 4) In the event of a negative demand shock, the digital factor sector increases research and development investment and accelerates technological breakthroughs to avoid a decline in profit margins, helping to maintain macroeconomic resilience and avoid drastic fluctuations in short-term total output. 5) The relative exclusivity of the digital elements sector may weaken the policy effectiveness of expansionary demand management.

The conclusion implies that in the digital economy, both initial demand shocks and demand policies aimed at rebalancing struggle to maximize short-term equilibrium changes. Therefore, macroeconomic rebalancing and long-term growth rely more on supply expansion or structured demand management policies combined with supply, and traditional regulatory measures would be partially ineffective. In recent years, China has implemented a series of institutional innovations in fiscal and monetary policies, coordinating with other policies, creating a new model for macroeconomic governance under the high-level socialist market economy system. This governance system fully considers the universal characteristics of the overall economic operation under the digital economy, aligning with the new characteristics of the macroeconomic rebalancing mechanism. It will continue to innovate and improve with the deepening development of the digital economy. Key points of this governance system include: 1) Maximizing the high-energy growth potential of the digital economy, synergistically promoting the regulation of total demand and the improvement of supply quality. 2) Unleashing the innovation-driven force of the digital economy, constructing a macro-resource mobilization, peak-adjustment, and allocation mechanism adapted to the cycle of digital technological innovations. 3) Forming a macro-governance system where macroeconomic policy is closely coordinated with industrial, regional, and other policies.

Downloads

Download data is not yet available.

References

[1] 习近平. 高举中国特色社会主义伟大旗帜 为全面建设社会主义现代化国家而团结奋斗: 在中国共产党第二十次全国代表大会上的报告 [M]. 北京: 人民出版社, 2022:30.

[2] LAFARRE A, ELST C V. Blockchain technology for corporate governance and shareholder activism [R]. Tilburg Law Schol Legal Studies Research Paper Series, 2018.

[3] ZHU C. Big data as a governance mechanism [J]. Review of Financial Studies, 2019, 32(5): 2021-2061.

[4] 戚聿东, 肖旭. 数字经济时代的企业管理变革 [J]. 管理世界, 2020(6): 135-152.

[5] 陈德球, 胡晴. 数字经济时代下的公司治理研究: 范式创新与实践前沿 [J]. 管理世界, 2022(6): 213-240.

[6] 祁怀锦, 曹修琴, 刘艳霞. 数字经济对公司治理的影响: 基于信息不对称和管理者非理性行为视角 [J]. 改革, 2020(4): 50-64.

[7] 许恒, 张一林, 曹雨佳. 数字经济、技术溢出与动态竞合政策 [J]. 管理世界, 2020(11): 63-84.

[8] 张晓. “数据驱动创新”的政策研究: 来自OECD的经验 [J]. 电子政务, 2020(3): 75-81.

[9] 张文魁. 数字经济的内生特性与产业组织 [J]. 管理世界, 2022(7): 79-90.

[10] NIU F. The role of the digital economy in rebuilding and maintaining social governance mechanisms [J]. Front Public Health, 2022, 9: 1-11.

[11] ALIM A, HOQUE M R, ALAM K. An empirical investigation of the relationship between e-government development and the digital economy: The case of Asian countries [J]. Journal of Knowledge Management, 2018, 22(5): 1176-1200.

[12] OBENDIEK A S. What are we actually talking about? Conceptualizing data as a governable object in overlapping jurisdictions [J]. International Studies Quarterly, 2022, 66(1): 1-13.

[13] 蔡跃洲. 中国共产党领导的科技创新治理及其数字化转型: 数据驱动的新型举国体制构建完善视角 [J]. 管理世界, 2021(8): 30-46.

[14] 战明华, 汤颜菲, 李帅. 数字金融发展、渠道效应差异和货币政策传导效果 [J]. 经济研究, 2020(6): 22-38.

[15] 谢星, 封思贤. 法定数字货币对我国货币政策影响的理论研究 [J]. 经济学家, 2019(9): 54-63.

[16] 姚前. 法定数字货币的经济效应分析: 理论与实证 [J]. 国际金融研究, 2019(1): 16-27.

[17] 李涛, 刘航. 数字经济学导论 [M]. 北京: 高等教育出版社, 2022: 22.

[18] 刘航, 张骥, 马斯曼. 从宏观经济调控到宏观经济治理: 现代化建设全局下完善宏观经济治理体系的逻辑与实践 [J]. 经济学家, 2023(10): 98-108.

[19] 卢斌典. 马克思主义再生产理论的思想内涵与逻辑演进 [J]. 马克思主义哲学, 2023(1): 82-89.

[20] 列宁全集: 第1卷 [M]. 中共中央马克思恩格斯列宁斯大林著作编译局, 编译. 北京: 人民出版社, 1955: 70-71.

[21] ARAUJO R A, DRUMOND C E. A two-sector Neo-Kaleckian model of growth and distribution: Investment allocation and evolutionary dynamics [J]. Metroeconomica, 2020, 72(1): 213-236.

[22] 王艺明, 刘一鸣. 马克思主义两大部类经济增长模型的理论与实证研究 [J]. 经济研究, 2018(9): 37-51.

[23] 李标. 新时代需求侧管理的政治经济学阐释 [J]. 马克思主义研究, 2022(7): 107-118.

[24] 马克思. 资本论: 第2卷 [M]. 中共中央马克思恩格斯列宁斯大林著作编译局, 编译. 北京: 人民出版社, 2004: 436-455.

[25] 徐志向, 丁任重. 中国经济增长驱动因素识别研究: 基于马克思扩大再生产理论的视阈 [J]. 政治经济学评论, 2020(2): 67-93.

[26] 徐志向, 丁任重, 张敏. 马克思社会再生产理论视阈下中国经济“双循环”新发展格局研究 [J]. 政治经济学评论, 2021(5): 40-63.

[27] 张衔. 马克思的社会资本再生产模型: 一个技术性补充 [J]. 当代经济研究, 2015(8): 5-14.

[28] 郭姵君, 苏勇. 中国奢侈品消费行为实证研究 [J]. 管理评论, 2007(9): 8-15.

[29] NUENO J L, QUELCH J A. The mass marketing of luxury [J]. Business Horizons, 1998, 41(6): 61-68.

[30] 吴宸梓, 白永秀. 数字技术赋能城乡融合发展的作用机理研究: 基于马克思社会再生产理论视角 [J]. 当代经济科学, 2023(6): 123-134.

Downloads

Published

2024-10-02

How to Cite

Theoretical Logic and Policy Practice of Digital Economy Driving the Improvement of Macroeconomic Governance System — An Analysis Based on Marx’s Theory of Social Reproduction. (2024). Modern Economic Science, 46(4), 1-13. https://doi.org/10.20069/ff78px02

Similar Articles

31-40 of 56

You may also start an advanced similarity search for this article.